MPT WWW
Leading policy-makers and scholars explain how market forces, deregulation, and consumer choice can work to improve health care for all Americans.

Commentary

Price Gouging is Bad Medicine
Alexander Tabarrok, Wall Street Journal, 5-20-06

Tabarrok, the co-author of a recent study on medical malpractice premiums for the Manhattan Institute, weighs in here with a powerful op-ed that demolishes arguments by plaintiff's lawyers and their allies that rising medical malpractice insurance premiums are the result of industry price gouging.

In what has become a biannual ritual, the Senate last week voted down medical malpractice reform. Reasonable minds might differ on the merits of federal legislation, but one thing's for certain: Medical malpractice insurance premiums are at an all–time high, and physicians are responding by retiring early, practicing more defensive medicine, and switching into less litigious specialties.

What's less certain, at least in the public debate, has been the cause of high insurance premiums. Doctors, led by the American Medical Association, attribute "rapidly increasing medical liability insurance premiums" to "escalating jury awards." Sen. Ted Kennedy, however, opposes federal reform because, as he told the New York Times, "the explanation for these premium spikes can be found not in legislative halls or courtrooms, but in boardrooms." His complaint echoes assertions by trial lawyers and their allied consumer groups like Americans for Insurance Reform that "price gouging" by wicked insurance companies is to blame for premium increases.

On its face, price gouging is a peculiar explanation for recent increases in insurance premiums. Is greed new to the world? Were insurance companies followers of Mother Teresa just a few years ago? If greed and gouging are the explanations for rising premiums, why did the St. Paul group—one of the nation's largest suppliers of medical malpractice insurance—pull out of the market in 2001? Were the profits from all that gouging just too much for St. Paul's guilty conscience? And consider that almost half of doctors are insured through mutual, i.e., doctor–owned, insurance companies. Are the doctors gouging themselves?

The gouging explanation fails more than the credulity test. Price gouging can work only if firms have monopoly power—so if gouging is the explanation for higher premiums, we would expect to see higher premiums in states with less competition. My student, Amanda Agan, and I tested this hypothesis in a study released two days ago by the Manhattan Institute. Contrary to the gouging hypothesis, we found that a 10% increase in industry concentration reduces premiums by $2,200. The result makes sense if we remember that, to increase market share, firms don't raise prices but rather lower them. Wal–Mart has grown into the nation's dominant retailer by lowering prices, not raising them...

Over the long run, insurance companies must cover their costs, so increases in premiums track increases in tort awards. As we show in our study, during the last 30 years every dollar increase in awards has led to a dollar increase in premiums. But tort awards are very difficult to predict because past awards tell us very little about future awards. Insurance companies, therefore, have a difficult job: They must predict future awards based on just a handful of the most recent awards. Was the latest multimillion dollar award a signal of permanently higher costs, or was it just a blip? Is tort reform working or were the more reasonable awards of the last year just a pause in the long upward trend?

Given the difficulty of forecasting awards, it's no surprise that insurance companies sometimes make mistakes. As a result, insurance companies can price premiums based upon a projection of future awards that are too low.

You never hear critics of the industry complaining of low prices, but we now know that prices in the 1990s were not high enough to cover the increase in tort awards. Recent increases in premiums are simply a belated recognition of the reality of what appears to be permanently higher medical malpractice awards. Since the insurance cycle is a function of the uncertainty of tort awards, not an independent cause of higher prices, the best way to dampen premium variation is to make tort awards more predictable.



Project FDA.
  
home   spotlight   commentary   research   events   news   about   contact   links   archives
Copyright Manhattan Institute for Policy Research
52 Vanderbilt Avenue
New York, NY 10017
(212) 599-7000
mpt@manhattan-institute.org